Maruti Crisis: Protestors demand release of innocent workers
By Abu Zafar,
newzfirst.com, July 21, 2012
NEW
DELHI – A large number of people Saturday protested against the
repression of workers at Maruti Suzuki plant, a leading car manufacturer
and urged government to act against management of the company and to
release innocent workers, who were arrested following violence inside
the plant on last Wednesday.
The protestors, who gathered outside Haryana Bhavan, shouting the
slogans against Bhupinder Hooda, the chief minister of Haryana and the
management of Maruti Suzuki Company, accused the management of
repressing the workers of the factory since a year.
Addressing the gathering of protestors, Shivkumar of Inquilabi
Mazdoor Kendra said, “Workers had long pending resentment against the
officials of management, who used to harass and abuse the workers for
trivial issues.”
He also expressed the deep anguish over the entire episode and death
of Awanish Kumar Dev. “We grieve over this unfortunate and painful
incident. And also deplore the move to make others scapegoat for this.”
He also held management of the plant, labor department and administration responsible for the entire incident.
In
Wednesday’s clash between workers and management staff, a senior
executive was killed and scores were injured. The management had pointed
the finger at workers for the violence inside the plant premises.
Police have arrested about a hundred workers in this case.
Protestors also accused the management for the violent developments,
who according to them called in the bouncers to brutally attack the
workers.
Protestors in the memorandum sent to chief minister of Haryana also
demanded an impartial probe by an independent agency. They also demanded
thorough investigation of security in-charge of the plant, who
according to protestors, will be in better position to reveal about the
bouncers.
Members of about two dozens of social and labor organizations joined the demonstration.
[This week's militant rebellion and
workstoppage of autoworkers at the Maruti Suzuki plant in the Delhi area
has brought with it typical (unsubstantiated) bourgeois media
speculation about Maoists or Naxalites sparking the whole thing off.
But, as Mao Zedong said, "Where there is oppression, there follows
resistance." It is the oppressive character of capitalist exploitation
itself that gives rise to the rebellion of the workers--at times, beyond
the limits of trade unionist arrangements. In this article, by RUPE's
journal "Aspects of India's Economy" the changing conditions the
autoworkers are confronting, are described. -- Frontlines ed.]
————————————————
Behind the Present Wave of Unrest in the Auto Sector
“Motown braces for wage revisions after three years”, reads a headline in the
Business Standard on
April 6, referring to wage negotiations in the Gurgaon-Manesar auto
belt. “Haridwar factories brew Manesar-like labour situation” warns
another headline in the same paper, reporting strikes at two major auto
parts suppliers. The Reserve Bank of India, in its latest “Monetary and
Macroeconomic Developments”, warns of the “pressure on generalised
inflation from sustained increase in wage costs”.
What is happening to industrial wage levels? Is the prosperity of
which the ruling establishment speaks now ‘trickling down’ to workers?
Do workers now have the upper hand, and are they grabbing a bigger share
of value added?
The last few years have indeed seen a rise in labour unrest,
particularly in the auto and auto parts sector. Among the prominent
instances are: Mahindra (Nashik), May 2009 and March 2011; Sunbeam Auto
(Gurgaon), May 2009; Bosch Chassis (Pune), July 2009; Honda Motorcycle
(Manesar), August 2009; Rico Auto (Gurgaon), August 2009, including a
one-day strike of the entire auto industry in Gurgaon; Pricol
(Coimbatore), September 2009; Volvo (Hoskote, Karnataka), August 2010;
MRF Tyres (Chennai), October 2010 and June 2011; General Motors (Halol,
Gujarat), March 2011; Maruti Suzuki (Manesar), June-October 2011; Bosch
(Bangalore), September 2011; Dunlop (Hooghly), October 2011; Caparo
(Sriperumbudur, Tamil Nadu), December 2011; Dunlop (Ambattur, Tamil
Nadu), February 2012; Hyundai (Chennai) April and December 2011-January
2012; and so on.
Unrest is not limited to the auto industry, but it has been centered
there. The auto industry has grown very rapidly in the last few years:
From 8.5 million vehicles (including two wheelers, three wheelers,
passenger vehicles and commercial vehicles) in 2004-05, production has
risen to 20.4 million in 2011-12. Passenger car production has risen
from 1.2 million vehicles in 2004-05 to 3 million in 2010-11 (and
probably further in 2011-12). The auto industry is a well-known ‘success
story’ of the rapid growth of the last decade, and the Government is
set on making India a global manufacturing ‘hub’ for automobiles, with
the help of large State subsidies.
1
On the other hand, it is a well-kept secret that real wages in the
auto sector – i.e., after discounting for inflation – actually
fell continuously
in the period 2000-01 to 2009-10. (The latest data available from the
Annual Survey of Industries [ASI] are for 2009-10.) True, annual wages
in the motor vehicles industry rose in
nominal terms from Rs 79,446 in 2000-01 to Rs 88,671 in 2004-05 to Rs 109,575 in 2009-10.
However, the Consumer Price Index for Industrial Workers (CPI-IW) consistently rose more steeply than wages. So
real wages in the auto industry fell
18.9 per cent between 2000-01 and 2009-10. (See Chart 1.)
On the other hand, net value added
2
per auto worker has been rising, barring a dip in the years of the
slowdown in the economy. Each worker added value of Rs 2.9 lakh in
2000-01; this figure rose by 2009-10 to Rs 7.9 lakh (see Chart 2).
Naturally, wages as a share of value added have been falling, as can
be seen in Chart 3. In 2000-01 workers’ wages were 27.4 per cent of
value added. By 2009-10, the ratio had fallen to 15.4 per cent.
To put this in Marxist terms, let us think of the working day as made
up of two parts. In one part the worker works to generate his/her
subsistence (and that of his/her family, thereby ensuring there will be
workers in future as well). In that time, the value the worker adds to the inputs is equivalent to the wage he/she gets.
3 But the worker can’t stop working at that point, because the capitalist has bought his/her
capacity to
work (labour power) for the full working day. (And the worker, owning
no means of production, has no choice but to sell that labour power in
order to survive.) He/she continues to labour for the rest of the
working day, whether it be a day of 8, 10, 12, or 16 hours. The
additional hours are surplus labour time, which we can also express in
money terms. This goes to the capitalist. Of course, the capitalist also
may pay, out of the surplus, interest to banks, rent to the owner of
the land, wages to management personnel, and so on, but all these others
take a share of the surplus
through the capitalist.
In these terms, we can say that in 2000-01, an auto worker spent 2 hours 12 minutes of an 8-hour shift working for his
4
own subsistence and that of his family. He spent most of the remaining 5
hours and 48 minutes generating surplus for the capitalist (and the
banks, landowners, management personnel, and so on). By 2009-10, the
ratio had deteriorated: The auto worker now spent just 1 hour 12 minutes
working for his own subsistence and that of his family, and the
remaining 6 hours 48 minutes working largely for the capitalist.
5
How did this deterioration take place? It was not merely a story of
growing worker productivity, the ability to produce more per hour with
new technology. As we saw above, workers’ wages actually
fell in real terms by almost one-fifth. Active class struggle was being waged –
by the employers against the workers.
One major front of this class struggle is the unwritten law against
the formation of independent unions in the auto sector. Perhaps the
single most important demand of the workers in recent agitations has
been the right to form their own union; in most cases workers have still
not been successful in doing so. Methods employed by the employers
include sacking, foisting of criminal cases, beating, and even killing.
The German auto parts manufacturer Bosch successfully resisted three
attempts at formation of a union. The story is the same everywhere –
Hyundai, Hero Honda, Wonjin, Maruti Suzuki, Graziano, Rico Auto. When
1,800 casual workers of the Dharuvera plant of Hero Honda sought to join
the union of their choice, cases under the Arms Act and Section 307 of
the Indian Penal Code (attempt to murder) were filed against the
leaders.
6
In Rico Auto, Gurgaon, workers were attacked by thugs in 2009,
leading to the death of one worker. In the Maruti agitation of 2011, the
Haryana labour department, indeed the entire Haryana government,
operated like a wing of the management. Auto firms are shifting their
operations to Gujarat, quite blatantly stating that they are doing so in
order to “union-proof” their production (i.e., they hope Mr Modi will
take care of such troublemakers).
An equally important, and complementary, method of wage-depression is
the hiring of contract, ‘trainee’, and ‘apprentice’ workers, at a
fraction of the wages of the permanent workers. According to news
reports, in the Gurgaon-Manesar-Bawal zone outside Delhi, which accounts
for about 60 per cent of auto production in India, 80 per cent of the
estimated one million workers are hired on contract.
7
In Maruti Suzuki’s Manesar plant, there were 970 permanent workers,
400-500 ‘trainees’, 1,100 contract workers, and 200-300 ‘apprentices’.
8
The situation is no different elsewhere in India. An Institute of
Economic Growth survey of workers in West Bengal and Gujarat found that
60-70 per cent of workers in manufacturing were contract labour – a
figure three three times that in the Annual Survey of Industries for
those states (ASI data are drawn from returns submitted by companies
themselves).
9The
last two decades have witnessed a massive growth in the share of
contract labour in the industrial workforce, even as the total workforce
has grown at a paltry rate.
Contract workers have been worst hit by price rise, since their wages
are not indexed. They have seen a steep fall in real wages. They have
reached the limit of their tolerance, and are now fighting back. It is
the attempt of workers to make up a part of their real wage losses over
the last decade, and particularly the last few years, or at least to
prevent a further slide, that accounts for their current increased
militancy.
Of course, auto workers are merely an outstanding instance of a general
trend. As can be seen from Charts 4 and 5, real wages in 2009-10 in the
factory sector as a whole were lower than in 2000-01, though the decline
was not as steep as in the auto sector. And wages as a proportion of
value added in the factory sector saw a steady decline over the period.
This
is the background to the rising incidence of what the media refer to as
violence – i.e., not the routine violence of the management, but the
resistance of the workers. Two recent examples: At Yanam (a pocket near
Kakinada, A.P., which belongs to Puducherry), 800 contract workers of
Regency Ceramics were on strike in January 2012 demanding
permanency and wage revision. The police attacked their picket lines
on January 27, killing their union president and injuring some others.
The enraged workers retaliated by attacking the president of the
company, resulting in his later death, and ransacking and burning
various properties of the owners. In Gurgaon, on March 19, 2012,
contract workers of Orient Craft (a garment exporter that supplies
international chains such as Tommy Hilfiger, DKNY and the Gap) protested
being docked two days’ pay for taking leave on Sunday. In response, a
contractor attacked a worker with a pair of scissors. The
thousand-strong workforce retaliated by burning down company vehicles
and a police car. The court released the contractor on bail and sent the
arrested workers to custody.
According to Labour Bureau data, the fall in real wages is not
restricted to industrial labour. Remarkably, despite the National Rural
Employment Guarantee Scheme (NREGS), real wages in the rural areas too
fell during the period 2004-05 to 2008-9.
10
This might be bad news for industries producing cheap mass consumption
goods, but they make up less and less of the corporate sector. Low rural
wages, and low rural incomes overall, have been good news for the
corporate sector in another sense: they have helped depress industrial
wages, because the alternative in the villages has been so bleak.
Notes:
1. See Aspects of India’s Economy no. 45,
http://www.rupe-india.org/44/private.html (
back)
2. The difference between the value of the physical inputs and the value of the output, minus depreciation. (
back)
3. To simplify this example, we ignore the need to replace worn-out machinery and other conditions of production. (
back)
4. Almost all auto workers are male. (
back)
5. These are the shares between one worker and
the capitalist; but of course the capitalist gets the surplus generated
by all the workers in his factory. So in a factory of 1,000 workers, the
capitalist gets 6,800 hours of surplus labour per day. (
back)
6. “MNCs can’t wish unions away”, Heena Khan,
Business Line (22/9/2011). (
back)
7. “Maruti workers-management talks to resume today”,
Business Standard (6/6/2011). (
back)
8. “Workers’ struggle in Maruti-Suzuki”, Prasenjit Bose and Sourindra Ghosh,
Hindu (28/9/2011). (
back)
9. 60-70 per cent of industrial workers in Bengal, Gujarat are contract labour”,
Business Line (22/7/2009). (
back)
10. See Yoshifumi Usami, “A Note on Recent Trends in Wage Rates”,
Review of Agrarian Studies, Vol. I, no. 1, January-June 2011,
http://ras.org.in/a_note_on_recent_trends_in_wage_rates_in_rural_india.
Usami writes: “nominal wage rates grew fast, but the deflator, i.e.
Consumer Price Index for Agricultural Labour and Consumer Price Index
for Rural Labour, rose much faster.” For some data of 2009-10, see
http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/the-truth-behind-rural-wages-in-india/452453/. (
back)